Proponents of the Efficient Market Hypothesis Reviewed by Momizat on . Always Want More Cowbell The More Cowbell skit can be repurposed to explain debates over the efficient market hypothesis. Many proponents of the efficient marke Always Want More Cowbell The More Cowbell skit can be repurposed to explain debates over the efficient market hypothesis. Many proponents of the efficient marke Rating: 0
You Are Here: Home » QuickRead Featured » Proponents of the Efficient Market Hypothesis

Proponents of the Efficient Market Hypothesis

Always Want More Cowbell

The More Cowbell skit can be repurposed to explain debates over the efficient market hypothesis. Many proponents of the efficient market hypothesis may initially find it annoying that nonbelievers do not share their view. However, believers’ faith in the efficient market hypothesis is dependent on nonbelievers continuing to try, but inevitably failing, to ‘beat the market.’ The efficient market hypothesis only works when investors can be ‘free riders’ that enjoy the fruits of nonbelievers’ labor, which make the market efficient. Thus, believers in the efficient market hypothesis should always want “more cowbell,” which in this context is nonbelievers who try to ‘beat the market.’ This is the first of a two-part article. This article addresses the efficient market hypothesis. The second article is titled: The Debate Over the Efficient Market Hypothesis’ Effect on Contested Valuations.

 

Summary/Introduction

Many fans of pop culture are familiar with Saturday Night Live’s “More Cowbell” skit.  Will Ferrell’s character (a member of the Blue Oyster Cult) annoyingly plays a cowbell during the band’s recording of “Don’t Fear the Reaper.”  After the other band members complain, Christopher Walken’s character (a successful music producer) counterintuitively proclaims: “I got a fever!  And the only prescription…is more cowbell!”  The previously annoyed band members, after hearing the music producer’s counterintuitive yet presumably informed and expert view, decide they want more cowbell too.

The More Cowbell skit can be repurposed to explain debates over the efficient market hypothesis.  Many proponents of the efficient market hypothesis may initially find it annoying that nonbelievers do not share their view.  However, believers’ faith in the efficient market hypothesis is dependent on nonbelievers continuing to try, but inevitably failing, to ‘beat the market.’  The efficient market hypothesis only works when investors can be ‘free riders’ that enjoy the fruits of nonbelievers’ labor, which make the market efficient.  Thus, believers in the efficient market hypothesis should always want “more cowbell,” which in this context is nonbelievers who try to ‘beat the market.’

This is the first of a two-part article.  This article addresses the efficient market hypothesis.  The second article is titled: The Debate Over the Efficient Market Hypothesis’ Effect on Contested Valuations.

Overview of the Efficient Market Hypothesis

The efficient market hypothesis (setting aside issues related to inside information)[1] posits that attempts to ‘beat the market’ are destined to fail.  Failure is inevitable because there are potential market participants trying to profit on both sides of a transaction and their efforts cancel each other out.  This results in a net loss for active investors as the costs they incur while trying to ‘beat the market’ exceed the excess returns generated from this endeavor.

Burton Malkiel provided one of the most colorful and famous descriptions of the efficient market hypothesis.  He stated, in his book A Random Walk Down Wall Street: “A blindfolded monkey throwing darts at a newspaper’s financial pages could select a portfolio that would do just as well as one carefully selected by experts.”  Perhaps nothing captures the essence of being unable to ‘beat the market’ better than the inability to beat a dart-throwing monkey in a security-picking contest.

Dependency on ‘Insane’ Investors

A common cliché is the so-called definition of insanity: repeating the same mistakes yet expecting different results.  The efficient market hypothesis is predicated on the assumption that there are many investors who continue to try, but consistently fail over the long-term, to ‘beat the market.’  It seems fair to say that proponents of the efficient market hypothesis have a symbiotic relationship with people they believe are ‘insane’ under this definition of ‘insanity.’

‘Low Cost’ vs. ‘Search for Alpha’ Investing Strategies

Perhaps the best way to classify someone’s view on the efficient market hypothesis is to identify how they invest their money.  Strong believers in the efficient market hypothesis are expected to invest in low cost index funds to obtain market-level returns at the lowest possible cost.  Strong disbelievers in the efficient market hypothesis are expected to invest in higher cost (i.e., actively managed) strategies with the expectation that above market returns on a cost-adjusted basis—i.e., alpha—can be achieved.  Investors who are less dogmatic, hedge their bets and fall somewhere in between these two ends of the continuum.

Which View is Correct?  The 2013 Nobel Prize Perspective

The 2013 Nobel Prize in Economics went to both the founder (Eugene Fama) and a leading critic (Robert Shiller) of the efficient market hypothesis.[2]  Awarding the prize to both, at the same time, was contemporaneously characterized as “unlikely,”[3] “seemingly contradictory,”[4] “shows a certain flair for irony;”[5] and was “like giving a prize to the Yankees and the Red Sox.”[6]  It seems fair to say that the selection of these economists for the Nobel Prize suggests the debate over the efficient market hypothesis may be unsettled.

The Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences (the group that awards the Nobel Prize), in the press release announcing the recipients, stated:

There is no way to predict the price of stocks and bonds over the next few days or weeks.  But it is quite possible to foresee the broad course of these prices over longer periods, such as the next three to five years.  These findings, which might seem both surprising and contradictory, were made and analyzed by this year’s Laureates, Eugene Fama, Lars Peter Hansen, and Robert Shiller.[7]

Warren Buffet: Do As I Say, Not As I Do

Many consider Warren Buffet to be the best example of someone who can consistently ‘beat the market.’  Mr. Buffet has famously made many more ‘winning’ than ‘losing’ investment-related decisions during his long tenure at the helm of Berkshire Hathaway.  This track record may make him the patron saint for value investing.

Mr. Buffett also appears to encourage this characterization as evidenced by the structure of Berkshire Hathaway’s annual report.  Immediately after the table of contents, without any introduction, is a table that compares the annual percentage change in (a) Berkshire Hathaway’s book value per share, (b) Berkshire Hathaway’s market value per share, and (c) the S&P 500 with dividends included for every year between 1965 and 2016.  There is no need to ‘tell’ readers about Berkshire Hathaway’s strong performance when it is more compelling to ‘show’ them.

As shown in Figure 1, $1 invested in Berkshire Hathaway stock on January 1, 1965 bought approximately $20,000 worth of Berkshire Hathaway stock as of December 31, 2016 whereas $1 invested in the S&P 500 index returned less than $130 during the same period.[8]  Thus, an investment in Berkshire Hathaway was worth greater than 150x more than an investment in the S&P 500 at the end of this 52-year period.

Figure 1[9]

This is a clear-cut case of a firm ‘clobbering the market’ over a sustained period.  This is not just a victory for active management.  This outcome is like the Bears beating the Redskins 73 to nothing in the 1940 NFL Championship Game, or Secretariat winning the Belmont Stakes by 31 lengths, which espn.com ranked as the worst (or best, depending on perspective) two blowouts in sports history.[10]

Nevertheless, Mr. Buffet believes it is extremely difficult to identify someone who is expected to consistently ‘beat the market’ as he and his colleagues have done during his long and successful career.  Mr. Buffet consistently advocates for investors to choose low cost index funds because they are expected to outperform actively managed funds on a cost-adjusted basis.  He also ‘puts his money where his mouth is’ in at least two important ways.

First, Mr. Buffet made a public bet, which put some money on the line but seems to be more about ‘bragging rights.’  He wagered that no investment professional could identify at least five hedge funds that could outperform the low-cost Vanguard S&P 500 index fund over a 10-year period.  Only one person took the other side of that wager: Ted Seides.  Mr. Seides picked five funds-of-funds.  It is now nine years into that bet with only one year to go.  As shown in Figure 2, it seems extremely likely that Mr. Buffet will win this bet.

Figure 2[11]

Second, Mr. Buffet put ‘his money where his mouth is’ in his personal will.  Mr. Buffett explained in the 2013 Berkshire Hathaway annual report:

My money, I should add, is where my mouth is: What I advise here is essentially identical to certain instructions I’ve laid out in my will.  One bequest provides that cash will be delivered to a trustee for my wife’s benefit…My advice to the trustee could not be more simple: Put 10% of the cash in short-term government bonds and 90% in a very low-cost S&P 500 index fund.  (I suggest Vanguard’s).  I believe the trust’s long-term results from this policy will be superior to those attained by most investors—whether pension funds, institutions, or individuals—who employ high-fee managers.[12]

Mr. Buffet’s rationalization for the ‘do as I say, not as I do’ advice appears to be that he believes he is one of the rarefied few who can repeatedly ‘beat the market.’  Mr. Buffet says he only identified early on (i.e., in time to substantially profit from the identification) “ten or so” professionals that were “highly likely to out-perform the S&P over long stretches.”[13]  He further states:

There are no doubt many hundreds of people—perhaps thousands—whom I have never met and whose abilities would equal those of the people I’ve identified.  The job, after all, is not impossible.  The problem simply is that the great majority of managers who attempt to over-perform will fail.  The probability is also very high that the person soliciting your funds will not be the exception who does well.[14]

This is an important observation for proponents of the efficient market hypothesis.  Mr. Buffet is perhaps the best person to lead the charge against the efficient market hypothesis.  However, he has not assumed the mantle in that debate.  To the contrary, he has effectively endorsed the efficient market hypothesis.

Notably, it is also not clear that Berkshire Hathaway has ‘beat the market’ for a while.  More specifically, it is not clear if Berkshire Hathaway would have won the bet shown in Figure 2.  As shown in Figure 3, Berkshire Hathaway appears, at least on the surface, to have underperformed relative to the S&P 500 during the nine-year term of the bet.

Figure 3

The discussion regarding Figure 3 is qualified because Berkshire Hathaway’s annual report may state that the change in the market value for its shares understates relative performance because it is on an after-tax basis whereas the change in the S&P 500 is on a pre-tax basis.  (“The S&P 500 numbers are pre-tax whereas the Berkshire numbers are after-tax [emphasis in original].”)  However, it is not clear if, or why, that logic applies to Berkshire Hathaway’s market value per share and not just its book value per share.  Also, if that logic does apply to Berkshire Hathaway’s market value per share, it is not clear why a similar disclaimer was not made to the data in Figure 2 within Berkshire Hathaway’s annual report.

Rise of the Machines

An increase in automation across many industries and disciplines seems inevitable.  This includes the security-picking profession.

BlackRock recently made an announcement that generated several ‘Rise of the Machine’ references.  Titles of podcasts or articles include “BlackRock: Rise of the Machines on Wall Street?” in the Wall Street Journal[15] and “At BlackRock, Machines are Rising Over Managers to Pick Stocks”[16] in the New York Times.

The New York Times article said:

The initiative is the most explicit action by a major fund management firm in reaction to the exodus of investors from actively managed stock funds to cheaper funds that track every variety of index and investment theme.

The Pendulum

It seems fair to say that the efficient market hypothesis’ efficacy will always be on a pendulum.  Active investors will seek to take advantage of perceived market inefficiencies, which subsequently results in fewer market inefficiencies.  Active investors will reduce their efforts as the market becomes more efficient, which in turn plants the seeds for more market inefficiencies down the road.

From a practitioner’s perspective, a key issue is the relevant range of the pendulum.  It may be fair to determine that a security’s price is ‘wrong’ because it is under- or overvalued on an intrinsic value basis.  But it is much harder to compellingly argue a security’s price is ‘wrong’ by (an) order(s) of magnitude.

The second part of this article will address this topic.

Conclusion

Debates over the efficient market hypothesis can be quite interesting.  Normally, a vigorous and well-prepared rebuttal by highly qualified and motivated people will cast doubt on the validity of the other side’s argument.  But this is no ordinary debate.  The debate is akin to fighting the monster in a science fiction movie that feeds off the energy used by the heroes in their attempt to defeat the monster.

The unusual nature of the debate results in a paradox: the more one fights it, the stronger the monster (or efficient market hypothesis) becomes.  It is for this reason that believers in the efficient market hypothesis should encourage dissent.  Simply put, proponents of the efficient market hypothesis can never have enough cowbell (aka dissent) as their demand for it is insatiable.

[1] Inside information is incorporated in the strong form, but not semi-strong or weak forms, of the efficient market hypothesis.

[2] Lars Hansen also was a recipient of the 2013 Nobel Prize in economics.  Dr. Hansen’s selection has been characterized as a “perfect balance” between the two extremes represented by Dr. Fama and Dr. Shiller.  https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2013-10-14/fama-hansen-shiller-share-nobel-economics-prize-academy-says

[3] https://mobile.nytimes.com/2013/10/15/business/3-american-professors-awarded-nobel-in-economic-sciences.html: “The two men, leading proponents of opposing views about the rationality of financial markets—a dispute with important implications for investment strategy, financial regulation, and economic policy—were joined in unlikely union Monday as winners of the Nobel Memorialize Prize in Economic Science (emphasis added).”

[4] http://www.economist.com/blogs/freeexchange/2013/10/economics-nobel-prize: “Together, Meers, Fama, Hansen, and Shiller make a seemingly contradictory group of people to win the prize together.  While Mr. Fama has been hailed as the father of the ‘efficient market’ hypothesis, Mr. Shiller is famous for knocking holes in the exact same theory.  Yet viewed in terms of their contributions, they are a more cohesive group (emphasis added).”

[5] https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2013-10-14/fama-hansen-shiller-share-nobel-economics-prize-academy-says: Andrew Lo, a finance professor at MIT’s Sloan School of Management said, “the Nobel committee’s decision in giving the award to Fama and Shiller ‘definitely shows a certain flair for irony.’  The message, he added is that ‘financial markets can be efficient most of the time, but every once in a while they break down and then we need to develop better analytics to be able to understand them (emphasis added).’”

[6] https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2013-10-14/fama-hansen-shiller-share-nobel-economics-prize-academy-says: “‘It’s like giving a prize to the Yankees and the Red Sox,’ [Robert Snow, winner of the Nobel economics prize in 1987] said, comparing the competing theories to the rivalry between the New York and Boston baseball teams.  ‘What it suggests is there really isn’t a settled doctrine’ in finance (emphasis added).”

[7] http://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/2013/press.html

[8] Berkshire Hathaway’s annual report explains that the data understates Berkshire Hathaway’s relative performance.  The most recent annual report states: “The S&P 500 numbers are pre-tax whereas the Berkshire numbers are after-tax.  If a corporation such as Berkshire were simply to have owned the S&P 500 and accrued the appropriate taxes, its results would have lagged the S&P 500 in years when that index showed a positive return, but would have exceeded the S&P 500 in years when the index showed a negative return.  Over the years, the tax costs would have caused the aggregate lag to be substantial (emphasis in original).”  This characterization makes sense for Berkshire Hathway’s book value per share.  It is not clear if, or why, that characterization is meant to apply to Berkshire Hathaway’s market value per share too.

[9] Data from p. 2 of Berkshire Hathaway’s 2016 Annual Report.

[10] http://www.espn.com/moresports/story/_/id/13670468/worst-blowouts-sports-history-ranks-100-most-stunning-routs-nos-25-1

[11] Data from p. 22 of Berkshire Hathaway’s 2016 Annual Report.

[12] Berkshire Hathaway’s 2013 Annual Report at p. 20.

[13] Berkshire Hathaway’s 2016 Annual Report at p. 24.

[14] Ibid.

[15] http://www.wsj.com/podcasts/blackrock-rise-of-the-machines-on-wall-street/0E12B88C-5996-4795-921D-D8EA87192A20.html

[16] https://www.nytimes.com/2017/03/28/business/dealbook/blackrock-actively-managed-funds-computer-models.html


Michael Vitti, CFA, joined Duff & Phelps in 2005. Mr. Vitti is a managing director in the Morristown office and is part of the Disputes and Investigations practice. He is also a member of the firm’s Complex Valuation and Bankruptcy Litigation group, focusing on issues related to valuation and solvency. Mr. Vitti has 20 years of valuation experience.
Mr. Vitti can be reached at (973) 775-8250 or by e-mail to michael.vitti@duffandphelps.com.

The National Association of Certified Valuators and Analysts (NACVA) supports the users of business and intangible asset valuation services and financial forensic services, including damages determinations of all kinds and fraud detection and prevention, by training and certifying financial professionals in these disciplines.

Number of Entries : 2537

©2024 NACVA and the Consultants' Training Institute • Toll-Free (800) 677-2009 • 1218 East 7800 South, Suite 301, Sandy, UT 84094 USA

event themes - theme rewards

Scroll to top
G-MZGY5C5SX1
lw