A Tale of Two Betas Reviewed by Momizat on . The Definition of Risk is Standard Deviation of Returns; Hereā€™s What it Means, and What it Has to Do with ā€œTotal Betaā€ Is the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) The Definition of Risk is Standard Deviation of Returns; Hereā€™s What it Means, and What it Has to Do with ā€œTotal Betaā€ Is the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) Rating:
You Are Here: Home » QuickRead Featured » A Tale of Two Betas

A Tale of Two Betas

The Definition of Risk is Standard Deviation of Returns; Hereā€™s What it Means, and What it Has to Do with ā€œTotal Betaā€

Is the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) superior as a valuation modeling tool to Total Beta? Peter J. Butler and Gary Schurman think not. Hereā€™s why:

Total Beta, and its resultant calculation of the total cost of equity, have received much scrutiny in the valuation profession since Total Betaā€™s introduction. Critics in the business valuation profession believe that the proponents of Total Beta misrepresent and mischaracterize modern portfolio theory, and contend that capital asset pricing model (CAPM) Beta is superior.

Applying modern portfolio theory, this article concludes that Total Beta stands head and shoulders above the CAPM Beta and the Build-up Method.

Risk and Diversification
The definition of risk in finance is the standard deviation of returns. The ability to diversify involves placing individual risky assets that are not perfectly correlated into a portfolio. If enough assets are placed into the portfolio, ļ¬rm-speciļ¬c risk is diversiļ¬ed away. In other words, all ļ¬rm-speciļ¬c risk is removed from the volatility, or standard deviation, of portfolio returns. According to traditional ļ¬nancial theory, since public investors have the ability to diversify away this ļ¬rm-speciļ¬c risk, it is not priced. Investors are, therefore, left with only systematic risk to worry about. As ļ¬nancial professionals, we all know, at least according to traditional ļ¬nancial theory, that systematic risk is captured by CAPM Beta. Ā (This article will not discuss the criticisms related to CAPM Beta or the newer theories which claim to capture additional systematic risks). What happens, though, if the investor cannot diversify away ļ¬rm-speciļ¬c risk?

The market for publicly traded stocks is dominated by institutional investors. Ā Because fund size is large, and both information and trading costs are low, institutional investors are in a position to diversify their holdings such that returns are maximized relative to the fundā€™s risk parameters. Diversiļ¬cation is further enhanced by the fact that the institutional investor is a ļ¬nancial buyer and does not seek control, so relatively small stakes in many public companies are not only possible but sought after. The institutional investor, who competes with other institutional investors for assets, bids up asset prices to the point where the investor is only compensated for systematic risk because ļ¬rm-speciļ¬c risks are Ā diversiļ¬ed away by all parties involved Ā in the equilibrium pricing process.

ā€œTotal Beta, a risk metric that captures total risk, is by far the most useful Beta for appraisers in valuing privately held companies most of the time.ā€

Well diversified, institutional investors are the marginal investors (as opposed to individual investors trading relatively small lots of stock) in many publicly traded stocks. In this case, marginal means that they set the price of the stock. The market for privately traded stocks, on the other hand, is dominated by the entrepreneur. The entrepreneur seeks control, and more often than not has limited resources such that true diversiļ¬cation is impossible. The institutional investor does not participate in this market due to high information and trading costs, which make a relatively small investment (from the institutional investorā€™s perspective) impractical. Individual investors (not to be confused with entrepreneurs) do not participate in the private market, because they do not have the wherewithal to analyze the investment in the absence of both public information and a market-determined equilibrium price. Given the absence of institutional investors, as well as individual investors, entrepreneurs are the marginal investors who set the prices for most private companies. Given the market frictions described above (information and trading costs and lack of resources), entrepreneurs are compensated for more than just systematic risk.

Firm-speciļ¬c risk is not completely diversiļ¬ed away by all parties involved in the equilibrium pricing process. In the case of the market for private stocks, investors demand, and receive, compensation for total risk (practically speaking) or at least something greater than systematic risk (theoretically speaking). Ā Of course, depending on the level of diversiļ¬cation, company-speciļ¬c risk will be priced in varying fashion. For Ā example, a sole proprietor who has all Ā of his net worth tied up in his company will price company-speciļ¬c risk completely, whereas a private equity fund, which is better able to diversify, may Ā price companies almost as if they were Ā publicly traded and therefore use something akin to the CAPM Beta. Ā 

The market structure described above results in an undiversiļ¬ed investor or at least not an optimally diversiļ¬ed investor; the business owner/entrepreneur or private equity fund does not hold a well diversiļ¬ed portfolio or an optimally diversiļ¬ed portfolio. CAPM Beta, therefore, does not capture all of the risk that is priced in the private markets. Therefore, CAPM Beta must be ā€œimprovedā€ or enhanced to ensure appraisers are capturing all of the systematic, as well as the un-diversiļ¬able ļ¬rm-speciļ¬c risk, being priced in the private markets. This article will show the modern portfolio theory behind a private companyā€™s Beta, as well as the practical applications of this improvement.

Deriving Private Company Beta

As a reminder, CAPM beta is deļ¬ned as:

Ī² = cov(s,m)/Ļƒ2m, [Equation 1]

which can be rewritten through mathematical substitution as:

Ī² = (Ļƒs/Ļƒm ) ĻsmĀ  [Equation 2]Ā 

where cov(s,m) is the covariance of the Ā stock with the market portfolio, Ā Ļƒ2m is the variance of the market portfolio, Ļƒs Ā is the standard deviation of the public Ā stock, Ļƒm Ā is the standard deviation of the market portfolio, and Ā Ļsm Ā is the correlation coeļ¬ƒcient between Ā the stock and the market portfolio.

To derive an appropriate private company Beta, we will deļ¬ne a business ownerā€™s (or an interested buyerā€™s) portfolio as a portfolio of only two assets: the stock of his or her private company and the market portfolio (as a simpliļ¬cation, we will use the S&P 500 Index). Letā€™s then assume that the percentage of net worth allocated to the private company is captured by Ļ‰. Therefore, the percentage allocated to the market portfolio equals (1 ā€“ Ļ‰) in our two-asset portfolio.

By deļ¬nition, the market portfolio has zero ļ¬rm-speciļ¬c risk. Therefore, all beneļ¬ts from combining these two assetsā€”the private company and the market portfolioā€”reduces the private companyā€™s stand-alone Beta, which is known in the business valuation profession as Total Beta. As the name implies, Total Beta captures total riskā€”all systematic as well as ļ¬rm-speciļ¬c riskā€”because it relies entirely on relative standard deviation, instead of correlated relative standard deviation (see Equation 2), as shown in Equation 3 below:

Total Beta = Ļƒs/ĻƒmĀ  Ā  [Equation 3]

The correlation coeļ¬ƒcient in Equation 2 can be viewed as the percent of total risk that is being priced by the public market. Viewed in this context, one minus the correlation coeļ¬ƒcient is the percent of total risk that is removed by diversiļ¬cation. Ā 

Notice the only adjustment we made to convert CAPM Beta to Total Beta was to set the correlation coeļ¬ƒcient equal to one in Equation 2, leaving a metric which captures the relative standard deviation between the stock and the market portfolio. In other words, if we add a stock to a portfolio which has perfect correlation with the portfolio, we have not gained any diversiļ¬cation beneļ¬t. So Total Beta is the appropriate Beta to use for private company valuation; if the private company is the only asset in a portfolio, then there is also no beneļ¬t from diversiļ¬cation. Ā (The Practical Application section below will look to see if Total Beta warrants more frequent use than only in ā€œstand-aloneā€ situations.)

However, given these assumptions, we have two assets in our hypothetical portfolio. The private business, in most cases, will comprise the majority of the portfolio and will deļ¬nitely not be perfectly correlated with the other asset (the market portfolio). In this two-asset portfolio some, but not nearly all, ļ¬rm-speciļ¬c risk is diversiļ¬ed away. Therefore, total risk will not be priced for the private company. Rather, some private-company Betaā€”a Beta greater than a CAPM Ā Beta proxy and less than a Total Beta proxyā€”will be the appropriate risk metric to develop a cost of capital for a private company. We call them proxies because, of course, we cannot directly observe any Beta for a private company.

As financial professionals, we also all remember the equation for portfolio return variance, Ļƒ p 2, for a two-asset portfolio as:

Ā Ļƒp2 Ā = Ļ‰2 Ā Ļƒs2 Ā + (1 – Ļ‰) 2 Ā Ļƒm2 Ā + 2Ļ‰(1 – Ļ‰)Ļƒs Ļƒm ĻsmĀ  Ā [Equation 4]

The variance of this portfolio depends on all systematic risk, as well as the ļ¬rm speciļ¬c risk not diversiļ¬ed away. Even though, in our assumption, the business owner already owned the market portfolio, by adding a private company to the mix and investing a large percentage of his or her net worth in that company, he or she has ā€œupset the apple cartā€ and is no longer well diversiļ¬ed.

How much of an assetā€™s total risk is not eliminated through this sub-optimal diversiļ¬cation and, therefore, priced in this scenario? Letā€™s ļ¬nd out below.

The risk-averse investor will not invest in a risky asset unless he or she expects to receive a return greater than the return from the riskless asset. The market price of risk is the additional return over the risk-free rate that risk-averse investors require per unit of volatility or unit of risk. Therefore, the market price of risk is measured as the expected return on the market portfolio, rm , in excess of the risk-free rate, r f , divided by Ā the standard deviation of returns of the Ā market portfolio:

Š¤ = (rm ā€“ rf )/ĻƒmĀ [Equation 5]

We will define the variable, Ī», as the Ā percent of the private companyā€™s Total Ā Beta that is not eliminated through diversification for a two-asset portfolio. The product of Total Beta and Ī», or (Ļƒs/Ļƒm )Ī», is the private-company Beta that Ā appraisers should use when valuing Ā closely held companies. (We will look at the practical application of this theoretical observation below.)

Using the market price of risk shown above, the annual rate of return required by a risk-averse investor, r s, is:

rs Ā = rfĀ  + Ļƒs Ī»Š¤ Ā [Equation 6]

While this equation may not look familiar, it is no diļ¬€erent in concept from the CAPM equation given as:

rs Ā = rfĀ  + Ī²(rm ā€“ rf )

rsĀ  = rfĀ  + (Ļƒs/ Ļƒm )Ļsm (rm ā€“ rf ) Ā [Equation 7]

where we assume investors are well diversiļ¬ed and therefore interested in Beta, (Ļƒs/Ļƒm )Ļsm , only as a measure of risk, Ā since all ļ¬rm-speciļ¬c volatility has been eliminated. In Equation 6 above, we take it as a given that all ļ¬rm-speciļ¬c risk is not completely eliminated when a private company is thrown into the mix. Business owners frequently place ā€œall of their eggs in one basketā€ (or at least most of their eggs) and, therefore, experience suboptimal diversiļ¬cation. Ā 

We also know that the expected return in an investorā€™s portfolio, r p, is the weighted average of the portfolioā€™s individual asset expected returns. For our two asset portfolio:

rp Ā = Ļ‰rsĀ  + (1- Ļ‰)rmĀ  Ā  Ā [Equation 8]

Substituting Equation 6 appropriately for rs and knowing that rm Ā is represented by:

rmĀ  = rfĀ  + Ļƒm Š¤; Ā  Ā [Equation 9]

where as proof:

Ā Š¤ = (rm – rf)/ ĻƒmĀ Ā Ā 

(see Equation 5 above) and substituting this for Š¤, results in rm = rm Ā in Equation Ā 8, we get

rpĀ  =Ļ‰(rf Ā + Ļƒs Ī»Š¤) + (1 – Ļ‰) ( rf Ā + Ļƒm Š¤)

rp Ā = rfĀ  + Ļ‰Ļƒs Ī»Š¤ + (1 – Ļ‰)Ļƒm Š¤ Ā  [Equation 10]

Since we want to price all risk (systematic and un-diversiļ¬able ļ¬rm-speciļ¬c) in our two-asset portfolio, the equation for portfolio expected return as a function of the market price of risk is:

rpĀ  =rfĀ  + Ļƒp Š¤ Ā [Equation 11]

which is the same concept as the theory behind Equation 9 above. We can now set Equations 10 and 11 equal to each other and solve for the only unknown, Ī».

rf + Ļ‰Ļƒs Ī»Š¤ + (1-Ļ‰) Ļƒm Š¤ = rf + Ļƒp Š¤

Ļ‰ĻƒsĪ»Š¤ + (1- Ļ‰)ĻƒmŠ¤ = ĻƒpŠ¤

Ļ‰ĻƒsĪ» + (1- Ļ‰)Ļƒm = Ļƒp

Ī» = (Ļƒp – (1- Ļ‰)Ļƒm)/Ļ‰Ļƒs Ā [Equation 12]

As a reminder, this is the amount of total risk that is not eliminated through diversiļ¬cation in the two-asset portfolio. Private business owners seek a risk premium over and beyond just systematic risk times the market price of risk. They may seek a risk premium equal to total risk (if the private business is considered the only asset in their portfolio) times the market price of risk. If they are partially diversiļ¬ed, then they will theoretically seek a risk premium less than the total risk premium, which Ī» helps capture.

Looking to Equation 6 above for guidance:

rsĀ  = rfĀ  + Ļƒs Ī»Š¤

rsĀ  = rfĀ  + Ļƒs Ī»(rm -rf )/Ļƒmwv

rsĀ  = rfĀ  + Ī» (Ļƒs /Ļƒm )(rm -rf ) Ā  Ā [Equation 13]

Where private-company

Beta = Ī»(Ļƒs /Ļƒm ) [Equation 14]

Compare this with Total Beta in Equation (3) above. As one can see, unless Ī» is 1.0 (a one-asset portfolio), thenĀ  the private-company Beta will be lessĀ  than Total Beta, but something greaterĀ  than CAPM Beta, Ļsm (Ļƒs /Ļƒm ).Ā 

In summary, Ī» will always be greater than the correlation coefficient, Ļsm , until we reach perfect diversiļ¬cationĀ  and hold the market portfolio. In anĀ  assumed two-asset portfolio, the diversiļ¬cation beneļ¬t will only approach ĻsmĀ  as the relative weighting essentially approaches a single-asset portfolio (i.e., 1%Ā  private company weight, 99%Ā Ā  market portfolio weight). Although one has to wonder if a hypothetical business owner ever reaches this relative weighting, what would be the point of owning a private business?

Substituting Equation (12) into (14) leads to:

Private-company Beta = ((Ļƒp – (1- Ļ‰)Ļƒm )/Ļ‰Ļƒs )(Ļƒs /Ļƒm )

Private-company Beta = (ĻƒpĀ  – (1- Ļ‰)Ļƒm )/Ļ‰ĻƒmĀ  [Equation 15]

Practical Applications
Letā€™s look at the practical side of this technique. As mentioned, appraisers look to the public markets for CAPM Betas (and now Total Betas). We will do the same to create Table 1.

Please keep in mind, these calculations are circular in nature. What we mean by that is we have to estimate the relative weighting of the two assets in the portfolio. However, before we know the relative weightings we have to value the private company, which depends on the private-company Beta.

As one can see in Table 1, all else being equal, the more weight assigned to a private company, the higher the Ī». This makes intuitive sense as the higher theĀ  weight, the closer the portfolio gets to a one-asset portfolio where Total BetaĀ  (Ī»=1.0) would be the appropriate metric to capture all risk.

Table 1: Changing Total Beta and Resulting Correlation Coeffecient
(Assumes standard deviation of market portfolio = 20%)

Ā 

Proxy

Ā 

Ā 

Ā 

Rounded

Ā 

% Wealth in Business

CAPM Beta

Total Beta

Correlation Coefficient

Private Co. Beta

Lambda

Standard deviation of Portiofio

100%

1.00

2.00

0.50

2.00

100.0%

40.0%

90%

1.00

2.00

0.50

1.95

97.4%

37.0%

80%

1.00

2.00

0.50

1.89

94.5%

34.4%

70%

1.00

2.00

0.50

1.82

91.0%

31.4%

60%

1.00

2.00

0.50

1.74

87.0%

28.8%

50%

1.00

2.00

0.50

1.65

82.5%

26.5%

40%

1.00

2.00

0.50

1.54

77%

24.3%

30%

1.00

2.00

0.50

1.42

71.0%

22.5%

20%

1.00

2.00

0.50

1.29

64.5%

21.1%

10%

1.00

2.00

0.50

1.15

57.5%

20.3%

1%

1.00

2.00

0.50

1.01

50.5%

20.0%

Graph 1: Portfolio Risk (Standard Deviation) And Portfolio Return

It appears that, practically speaking, the private company dominates the risk of the two-asset portfolio. We ran calculations for a few other scenarios, altering the CAPM Beta, Total Beta and correlation coeļ¬ƒcient, and generally found the following results:

  • At an equal 50-50%Ā  weighting given our assumptions, more than 80%Ā  of the total risk of the private company is still priced. Ā 
  • At a 70%Ā  private company and 30%Ā  market portfolio weighting, more than 90%Ā  of total risk is still priced. Ā 
  • At an 80%Ā  private company and 20%Ā  market portfolio weighting, approximately 95%Ā  of total risk is priced. Ā 
  • At a 90% and 10%Ā  weighting, approximately 98%Ā  of total risk is still priced.

These large weightings, biased toward the private company, are realistic for many business owners/entrepreneurs.

We also show in Graph 1 how portfolio return and risk would look under diļ¬€erent private company weightings, depending on the following assumptions (derived from Table 1):

  • Risk-free rate = 5%Ā 
  • Market price of risk = 0.3Ā 
  • Market portfolio volatility = 20%Ā 
  • Private company volatility = 40%Ā 
  • Private-company Beta = 1.0 (like the marketā€™s Beta)Ā 
  • Correlation coeļ¬ƒcient between theĀ  private company and the marketĀ  portfolio = 0.5Ā 

In summary, as you increase the weightĀ  of the private company in the portfolio,Ā  the risk and return both increase due toĀ  sub-optimal diversiļ¬cation.

Ā 
Conclusions
These results confirm that Total Beta, a risk metric that captures total risk, isĀ  by far the most useful Beta for appraisers in valuing privately held companiesĀ  most of the time.

Given the inherent subjectivity in estimating weightings, the circular nature of the calculation, and the apparent lack of sensitivity to realistic weightings (90-10% , 80-20% , 70-30% , etc.), it may make sense to just calculate a proxy Total Beta for a privately held company. Practically speaking, estimating the relative diversiļ¬cation of the expected pool of buyers is a rather subjective, and not terribly sensitive, exercise.

For what itā€™s worth, we also believe that most, if not all, valuators and business brokers value/price privately held companies as stand-alone assets. It appears that this assumption has not been an ā€œincorrectā€ decision, at least from a practical perspective. Having said that, we do recognize that Total Beta is not appropriate in all situations, such as when a private company is going public; when a public company is buying a private company; or when the likely pool of investors/purchasers can be considered diversiļ¬ed on some level, such as possibly a private equity fund that is investing across a wide variety of industries.Ā  As a reminder, there are two assumptions that underlie the use of Total Beta:

  1. The investor is not diversiļ¬ed or is sub-optimally so.
  2. Ā The investor can fully price for the risk associated with this lack of diversification.

Appraisers who add company speciļ¬c risk premiums accept these two assumptions by default because:

    1. Why would the appraiser add a company-speciļ¬c risk premium if the investor can indeed diversify away company-speciļ¬c risk?Ā 
    2. Why would the appraiser add a company-speciļ¬c risk premium if the investor cannot fully price for this additional risk?

Appraisers who do not accept these two assumptions as fact cannot add company-speciļ¬c risk premiums regardless of how these risk premiums are calculated (Total Beta, build-up method, etc.).

Moreover, since Total Beta captures total risk in an empirical manner, appraisers are no longer required to make educated guesses, with no empirical data to use as a proxy, regarding an appropriate ļ¬rm-speciļ¬c risk premium.Ā  This is its major contribution to the business valuation profession. When Total Beta (private-company Beta) is employed, it empirically captures all systematic and ļ¬rm-speciļ¬c risk that is practically (theoretically) priced.Ā  Hence, Total Beta lives up to its name and captures all pertinent risks that appraisers must price.

This article was originally published in the January/February 2011 issue of The Value Examiner.

Peter J. Butler, MBA, CFA, ASA, is the founder and principal of Valtrend, LLC, in Eagle, ID, which provides business valuation, litigation support, and ļ¬nancial advisory services (www.valtrend. com). He is inventor and co-developer of the Butler Pinkerton Calculator.

Gary Schurman, CPA/ ABV, MBE, CFA has over 25 years of experience in finance, accounting, and software development.Ā  He is currently a principal in Applied Business Economics (www. appliedbusinesseconomics.com). His practice areas include business valuation (equity, debt, preferred stock, options, etc.), business consulting, capital markets advisory, structured ļ¬nance advisory, ļ¬nancial model building, and software consulting. He is the author of ā€œValuing Loan Guarantees,ā€ in the November/December VE 2010 issue of The Value Examiner.Ā 

The National Association of Certified Valuators and Analysts (NACVA) supports the users of business and intangible asset valuation services and financial forensic services, including damages determinations of all kinds and fraud detection and prevention, by training and certifying financial professionals in these disciplines.

Number of Entries : 2611

Ā©2024 NACVA and the Consultants' Training Institute ā€¢ Toll-Free (800) 677-2009 ā€¢ 1218 East 7800 South, Suite 301, Sandy, UT 84094 USA

event themes - theme rewards

Scroll to top
G-MZGY5C5SX1
lw